Tuesday, September 02, 2014 / PROGRESSIVE JOURNALISM FOR POSITIVE ACTION
Get Email Updates | Log In | Register

Christopher Petrella
NationofChange / Op-Ed
Published: Tuesday 11 September 2012
A revolving door is inefficient, so too is cronyism.

Prison Privatization and the Efficiency Myth

Article image

In 2010—the most recent year for which reliable records exist—privately owned and/or operated prisons held 128,195—or roughly eight percent— of the 1,612,395 total state and federal prisoners in the U.S. The figure of 1.6 million, mind you, doesn’t include populations residing in municipal jails, as an additional 700,000 individuals languish in local facilities

On the federal level exclusively, 28,462—or thirteen percent— of the federal Bureau of Prison’s (hereafter ‘the Bureau’) 218,081 inmates are housed in privately managed facilities around the country. Although many rightly decry the Bureau’s burgeoning inmate populations since 2000, a striking number of influential prison policy analysts still fail to notice that of the sixteen privately managed Bureau facilities more than half (ten, to be precise) were awarded contracts beginning the 1990s.  That the Bureau began contracting in earnest with private corrections companies in the mid-1990s matters, and here’s why.

Correctly periodizing the Bureau’s affiliation with private management firms is critical for de-naturalizing the dusty assumption that privatization can be trusted as a policy solution for its ability to generate efficient markets.  That is, properly contextualizing the rise of the Bureau’s private contracts assails the most popular claims made by apologists of privatized corrections. Devotees of business-model punishment often assert that 1) privatization introduces competition into an otherwise public monopoly thereby enhancing services throughout the system while lowering the overall cost and 2) that private prisons can provide the same or better services at a lower cost than the public sector because the marketplace forces efficiency and innovation.

Contrary to popular belief, however, the initial justification for privatizing the Bureau’s facilities was not the result of economic necessity, but instead the indistinct outcome of a number of intersecting political (electoral) imperatives.

During the fall of 1993 the Clinton White House found itself caught between two seemingly contradictory political objectives: 1) locking up more “criminals” to appear “tough on crime” and 2) reducing the size of the federal workforce to propitiate conservatives.  Both aspirations emerged from Clinton’s 1992 campaign promises to shrink the size of the government while simultaneously incarcerating more individuals in federal prisons for longer sentences. Remember that in 1994 President Clinton signed into law both a federal “Truth in Sentencing” bill requiring offenders to serve at least 85 percent of their sentence before becoming eligible for parole and the Violent Crime and Law Enforcement Act which created over sixty new death penalty offenses, rendered prisoners ineligible from receiving Pell grants to participate in post-secondary degree programs while incarcerated, and provided funds to hire an additional 100,000 police officers to enforce drug-related crimes.

These two objectives inevitably collided. Building more facilities to meet a quickly growing field of prisoners, of course, would require hiring thousands of new employees just as the federal government was supposed to be shrinking. And so how did the Clinton Administration solve its seemingly insuperable problem?

Three words: Private prison contracts.

Per the recommendation of President Clinton the Bureau reluctantly agreed to use private companies to manage most new federal prisons; the employees at these would not show up on the department's official payroll. 

In endorsing his prison privatization plan, President Clinton embraced the concepts behind the National Performance Review, Vice President Al Gore's 1993 study to reinvent government so that it "works better and costs less," especially the commitment to cut between 100,000-250,000 federal employees from the payroll. (It’s important to recall that in 1993 the total federal workforce had already dipped below Reagan-era thresholds...) In the case of prisons, Clinton’s hypothesis was that after reducing federal personnel, Washington D.C. would then turn to private contractors to do their work. 

The federal Bureau of Prisons awarded nine more contracts before the election of George W. Bush thanks in part to the revolving door between private corrections companies and federal law enforcement agencies beginning in the 1990s.

It’s more than a bit ironic, for instance, that in early 1993, Michael Quinlan, Director of the Federal Bureau of Prisons from 1987-1992, was recruited to work for the Corrections Corporation of America (CCA), the nation’s largest private prison firm. Since Quinlan’s arrival the Bureau has awarded contracts to private corrections firms nearly on a yearly basis. And the trend persists to this very day. Less than two years ago President Obama nominated Stacia Hylton as the new Director of the United States Marshals Service (USMS). Just months before her nomination, Hylton agreed to a consulting contract with The GEO Group—the nation’s second largest private prison operator— worth $112,500. 

A revolving door is inefficient, so too is cronyism. Cronyism, by its very preferential nature, is antagonistic to the notion of fairness in competition, supposedly the bulwark of modern capitalism.  Despite the popular taken-for-granted ideology that privatization spawns efficiency, there is no evidence to suggest that the Clinton administration—the vanguard of federal prison privatization—believed that private firms were any more effective than the Bureau at containing and rehabilitating prisoners. Clinton’s calculus was political, not empirical. My hope here is that a brief sweep of past privatization debates will help us to challenge the sweeping partisanship of those in the present.



Author pic
ABOUT Christopher Petrella

Christopher Petrella is a NationofChange contributing author and a doctoral candidate in African American Studies at the University of California, Berkeley. He writes on the contradictions of modernity and teaches at San Quentin State Prison. His work has appeared in such publications as Monthly Review, Truthout, Axis of Logic, NationofChange, and The Real Cost of Prisons. Christopher also holds degrees from Bates College and Harvard University.

It would be the ultimate

It would be the ultimate justice to place these advocates for private prisons in their own prisons for a few years.

don't just look at prison

don't just look at prison privatation - overall it is a bad deal. here in New Jersey when Christine Whitman was governor the move was to privatize Motor Vechicle - first step was to double all the fees - to make it prifitable enough to sell the idea........ok. next came the farce of not watching what was going on and drivers licenses were up for sale....NEXT came the buy backs to re-claim the Motor vechicle offices......DUH....the fees never went back down
The STATE can run something without making any hugh profit......private industry wants all it can get and isn't fussy about how they get their money..
BAD MOVE

What the most egregious

What the most egregious fallacious assumption of the USAmerican criminal-injustice system? That periods of time in the torture chambers that ARE U.S. prisons and jails will have ANY positive effect on crime!

As for privatization, here in Arizona previously mandated reports proved that the private prisons are MORE expensive than the public ones - even with their ability to cherry-pick the least troublesome inmates. In response, the bat-crap crazy Arizona Legislature just outlawed the report...

Concentration camps are

Concentration camps are "efficient". Surely no one would recommend them for use as part of our ever-growing prison system. What is needed is an impartial examination of why the prison population continues to grow and solutions that will help keep people out of prison in the first place. The proverbial ounce of prevention will no doubt cost far less than the current tons of care.

They didn't pretend they were

They didn't pretend they were "corrections" institutions in Russia.
They called them "Gulags" and were nothing more or less than forced labor camps.
So, let's ask: How are you going to make a "profit" from prisons if you can't force the detainees to work for you?
It used to be called "Slavery"... and is still slavery, pretend how you will.

We already HAVE concentration

We already HAVE concentration camps rhetorically disguised as "prisons" and "jails"!

They are MEANT to be warehouses for excess workers, mostly of Color, who aren't needed by the capitalist masters and by being incarcerated won't increase the "level of unemployment". They're doing their appointed task.

Anytime government outsources

Anytime government outsources its duties to a for profit corporation, there is no savings. Prisons, medical care, war, etc. should NEVER be outsourced to for profit corporations.

Comment with your Facebook account



Comment with your Disqus account

Top Stories

NationofChange works to educate, inform, and fight power with people, corruption with community.

If you would like to stay up to date with the best in independent, filter-free journalism, updates on upcoming events to attend, and more, enter your email below:

The most complete GMO-free living guide.

Your GMO guide is here

Click here to sign up to receive the NationofChange e-newsletter and receive our complimentary guide, "No GMO", NationofChange's guide for GMO-free living.